Can We Blame Keynes for Keynesianism?

Posted in Politics
Wed, Apr 8 - 9:00 am EST | 3 years ago by
Comments: 2
Be Sociable, Share!
    Use Arrow Keys (← →) to Browse

    The Good Life - Keynesianism

    In our era of Keynesian economics on steroids, we should ask: How close is current Keynesian practice to original Keynesian theory?

    John Maynard Keynes‘s main claim to fame is his advocacy of deficit spending as a tool of economic recovery. In a depressed economy, the argument runs, the government should spend money it doesn’t have. That will stimulate demand, which in term will stimulate supply. Once the economy is back on track, tax revenues will increase, which the government can use to offset its deficits. Thus, in the medium-term its books will happily balance.

    Before Keynes some economists had urged the occasional use of deficit spending to counter downturns. Keynes’s originality was placing that particular political policy tool within the context of a more general economic theory.

    But since Keynes’s 1936 General Theory, we’ve experienced decades of deficits and accelerating government debt. So what went wrong?

    I’ve been re-reading James Buchanan and Richard Wagner’s seminal Democracy in Deficit: The Political Legacy of Lord Keynes. Buchanan won the Nobel Prize in 1986 for pioneering Public Choice theory or “politics without romance,” as he called it.

    Democracy in Deficit is essential reading for all political thinkers, and two of its points about assessing Keynes’s responsibility strike me as important.

    First, Keynes was a political elitist, not a democrat. Buchanan and Wagner quote biographer R. F. Harrod on Keynes’s ongoing assumption “that the government of Britain was and could continue to be in the hands of an intellectual aristocracy using the methods of persuasion.” So perhaps Keynes thought his prescriptions should not be applied in a democracy. Only an aristocracy of intelligent and disciplined politicians could be trusted with Keynesian policies.

    After all, what kind of politician typically gets democratically elected? Don’t they tend to be more cunning than intelligent, more pandering and less disciplined? So Keynesianism in a democratic context will lead to misdirected and out-of-control spending — and here we are today. But we can’t blame aristocratic Keynes for democratic Keynesianism, so we must shift the blame to his followers who abused his system and misapplied it.

    Second, Keynes’s General Theory was published in 1936 and was in part responsive to the Great Depression. Emergency government measures were needed, the argument ran. But those emergency measures would and should be suspended once the emergency had passed. So a decade later — after the Depression and World War II — Keynes’s theory says to stop the deficit spending. But Keynes died in 1946, and if his disciples continued to apply his methods that is not Keynes’s fault.

    So is Lord Keynes off the hook?

    Keynes’s theory is subject to three types of criticism. One type is moral: A great achievement of the modern world had been an expansion in human freedom — getting the governments out of religion, eliminating much censorship, ending slavery, expanding the range of women’s liberties, and freeing up markets. The economy should be a network of voluntary trades. But the government is an agency of coercion, as everything it does is backed up by the police, the military, and the prison system. Yet Keynes is for reintroducing government compulsion into the economy. This criticism is made strongly by Ayn Rand, for example.

    Another criticism is cognitive: Keynes’s theory asks politicians and other central planners to have an accurate God’s-eye view of the economy. But that’s impossible. Another achievement of the modern world has been its social-scientific understanding of how prices work to coordinate the knowledge and actions of millions of individuals, each of whom knows his or her own values and circumstances best. Distant economic planners, however intelligent, can only make crudely macro estimations. This criticism is made strongly by Friedrich Hayek, for example.

    The Public Choice criticism of Buchanan, by contrast, focuses on incentives: Keynes’s great mistake was to ignore or downplay the role of incentives in a political context. Keynes’s advice was in part for nations like Great Britain and the United States, and each of them, Keynes knew, had significant democratic elements, so he should have taken that into account.

    (Interestingly, the first two translations of the General Theory were published in Germany and Japan, and in his 1936 prefaces to those editions Keynes noted that his ideas would likely meet more receptivity in those nations than in the United States.)

    For example, Franklin D. Roosevelt may have been the sort of semi-aristocratic “economic statesman” that Keynes had in mind. And in 1932 candidate Roosevelt strove for the high ground: “Let us have the courage to stop borrowing to meet continuing deficits … I know a continuation of that habit means the poorhouse.” But once elected, President Roosevelt realized more pointedly that spending programs were enormously popular politically and that taxes and spending cuts were frighteningly unpopular.

    So Keynes was at least naĂŻve. He should have been able to foresee what politicians will do. ”We can pay for it later, somehow” is seductive for many people, even when it’s their own money. But it’s irresistible to politicians, especially when they are spending other people’s money.

    Also, there is always some “emergency” that can be seen as needing spending to fix it — and there are always economists who enjoy being close to the seats of power and who will tell the politicians what they want to hear. Ongoing spending can always be rationalized.

    Those criticisms of Keynes are strong.

    But the most important point is that Keynes was not merely recommending a few surgical interventions to smooth out cycles or to jump-start moribund economies. Keynes’s economics are part of a comprehensive interventionist philosophy of morality and politics.

    Long before the Depression — and long before the new theoretical elements of the General Theory — Keynes was already a strong opponent of free-market capitalism.

    In 1926, for example, he published The End of Laissez-Faire, in which he criticized harshly free-market capitalism and pushed for substantial socialization of the economy. Socialism, he argued, had moral merit because it “departs from laissez-faire”: socialism “takes away from man’s natural liberty to make a million” and opposes “unlimited private profit.” As Keynes said forthrightly, “All these things I applaud.”

    He also agreed with socialists that the government should provide “the deliberate control of the currency and of credit by a central institution.”

    But Keynes was not a socialist, and he criticizes the authoritarianism necessarily built into socialism. His goal was to make attractive a principled middle way between the extremes of capitalist freedom and socialist control.

    Individuals should be allowed their own private savings, Keynes agrees. The government should only control and direct savings at the macro level: “a coordinated act of intelligent judgment is required as to the scale on which it is desirable that the community as a whole should save.” Additionally, it should be the government’s decision about how much of those “savings should go abroad in the form of foreign investments.”

    Keynes also allows that many businesses can and should remain private. But “many big undertakings, particularly public utility enterprises and other business requiring a large fixed capital, still need to be semi-socialised” (italics added).

    As for sex and family life, the government should stay out of people’s bedrooms. Nonetheless, Keynes urges, “each country needs a considered national policy about what size of population, whether larger or smaller than at present or the same, is most expedient.” Not only that — in a nod to eugenic theory — Keynes argues that “the community as a whole must pay attention to the innate quality as well as to the mere numbers of its future members.”

    All of this and more is Keynes in the 1920s. By the time the General Theory is published a decade later, Keynes has not changed his fundamental political philosophy but rather has advanced in the sophistication of the economic tools that he makes available for realizing it.

    Keynes may have called for very nuanced uses of this or that policy. He likely would have had ongoing arguments with his followers’ judgments about precisely when and how to implement those policies. And he may have underestimated significantly the difficulty of translating clean economic theory into messy political practice.

    But he did advocate a robustly interventionist economic system in principle. He did provide a sophisticated set of tools for policymakers to use when intervening. And he did give a bright green go-ahead light for politicians to apply his theories to real human beings in the real economy.

    The huge influence that Keynes has enjoyed for precisely those points is the most any theorist can hope for. Keynes owns the results.

    Stephen Hicks is the author of Explaining Postmodernism: Skepticism and Socialism from Rousseau to Foucault and of Nietzsche and the Nazis. He blogs at StephenHicks.org. For future columns on The Good Life, feel welcome to send your philosophical questions and moral dilemmas to him at ProfessorHicks@EveryJoe.com.

    Note: If you follow the retail links in this post and make purchases on the site(s), Defy Media may receive a share of the proceeds from your sale through the retailer’s affiliate program.

    Keep up with the best of The Good Life below. Click through the gallery to read more from Stephen Hicks.


    Profit

    Nobody likes to lose money, but profit generates polarized attitudes.

    Photo by Melpomenem/Getty Images

    Money and books

    Which is more evil - loving money or books?

    Photo by Getty Images

    Campus Politics

    Universities are political places, but there’s good politics and bad.

    Photo by Getty Images

    Immigration

    Stephen Hicks discusses the limits to open immigration.

    Photo by Jordan Pix/Getty Images

    Terrorism

    Stephen Hicks explores how to tame religious terrorists.

    Photo by Thierry Chesnot/Getty Images

    Schooling

    Is education really too expensive?

    Photo: monkeybusinessimages / Getty Images

    Sexbots

    Let's discuss the ethics of having sex with robots.

    Photo by Jiri Miklo/Getty Images

    Comparing North and Latin America

    Stephen Hicks explores why there are such dramatic differences in economic performance between the two Americas?

    Photo: Anson_iStock / Getty Images

    Free College Tuition Is a Moral Issue

    Many successful people did not graduate from college and many unsuccessful people have impressive degrees. So who should go to college? And who should pay for it?

    Photo: Rawpixel Ltd / Getty Images

    Hitler

    Stephen Hicks explores answers to the question, "How smart and well-read was Adolf Hitler?"

    Microaggression

    Read Part I and Part II in this series on understanding triggers and microaggression as strategy.

    Greece

    Stephen Hicks weighs in on Greeek debts and doing what's moral.

    Free Speech

    Times are changing. Is Free Speech Dead in Universities?

    Intelligence

    Stephen Hicks talks about intelligence, freedom, and who knows what's best for you. Also don't miss his piece entitled, "Are You Smart Enough to Live in a Free Society?

    Economics

    How close is current Keynesian practice to original Keynesian theory? Can we blame Keynes for our current situation?

    Philosophy

    Philosophy has a reputation for attracting deep thinkers whose quest for wisdom can serve as a model for all of us. And since politics is a major component of the life well lived, what wisdom can philosophy bring to bear on politics? Are philosophers stupid about politics?

    Poverty

    Let us share with you the most impressive number of our generation: 600 million. That is how many people have been lifted out of extreme poverty in the last 25 years. Read more about the the problem of poverty.

    Sex

    Controversy has been running high recently over how best to lower the rape rate on campuses. Read Stephen Hicks' piece on Campus Sex and the Anti-Sexiness of the New Authoritarians.

    Money

    Stephen Hicks weighs in on the economy, deregulation, capitalism and much more.

    Power

    As with sex and money — and most of the important matters in life — many silly things are said about power. Find out why power does not corrupt, and it's character that matters most.

    Elections

    Cynicism about money in politics is a healthy response to our long history of cronyism, but does money really buy elections?

    Schizophrenic Politics

    Let’s talk about one reason why politics makes us all a little crazy — its incoherent mix of laws and regulations. So what should governments really do? Read about Our Schizophrenic Politics from Stephen Hicks.

    Lifeboat Ethics

    Don't miss this two-part series from Stephen Hicks about lifeboat ethics:

    Use Arrow Keys (← →) to Browse

    Be Sociable, Share!

      Related Posts

      • Bordeaux Vixen

        good for this relative idiot?

      • Edward Fox

        “Keynes did not teach us how to perform the ‘miracle . . . of turning a stone into bread,’ but the not at all miraculous procedure of eating the seed corn.”
        – Ludwig von Mises, Planning for Freedom, p. 71

      Be Sociable, Share!